globalchange  > 气候变化事实与影响
DOI: doi:10.1038/nclimate2259
论文题名:
A compromise to break the climate impasse
作者: Marco Grasso
刊名: Nature Climate Change
ISSN: 1758-1277X
EISSN: 1758-7397
出版年: 2014-06-08
卷: Volume:4, 页码:Pages:543;549 (2014)
语种: 英语
英文关键词: Social scientist/Social science ; Geography/geographer ; Sociology/sociologist ; Environmental economics/Economist ; Climate policy ; Environmental policy ; Global change ; Earth system science ; Climatologist ; Climate science ; Carbon management ; Carbon markets ; Energy ; Renewables ; Palaeoclimatology/Palaeoclimatologist ; Climate modelling/modeller ; Carbon cycle ; Atmospheric scientist ; Oceanography/marine science ; Sustainability ; Geophysicist/Geophysics ; Biogeoscience/Biogeoscientist ; Hydrology/Hydrogeology ; Greenhouse gas verification ; Ecologist/ecology ; Conservation ; Meteorology/meteorologist
英文摘要:

To overcome the current impasse in global climate negotiations we propose a compromise for sharing the remaining carbon budget, based on four elements. First, limiting initial action to the Major Economies Forum members would streamline negotiations greatly. Second, using consumption-based carbon accounting would overcome important fairness concerns of key developing countries. Similarly, applying equity principles of responsibility and capability to apportion the burden of emissions reductions within the group can address concerns of both the global north and south. And fourth, promptly bringing this compromise back to the United Nations negotiations for wider adoption will be critical. Based on an indicative carbon budget of 420 gigatonnes carbon dioxide over the period 2012–2050, our analysis shows that ambitious but feasible emissions reductions will be needed, with sharp differences by world economic groups. The compromise offers effectiveness, feasibility and fairness.

The international community is struggling to find a strategy for breaking the enduring gridlock on climate change. In terms of international cooperation to adequately address the climate crisis, the most urgent and complicated coordination problem is the development of an inclusive, concerted framework for promptly abating greenhouse gas emissions1. Such a framework must meet three criteria: effectiveness, feasibility and fairness.

As negotiations move towards the 2015 deadline to settle a successor treaty to the Kyoto Protocol, pressure is building to have an agreement that covers all countries, including India and China, in commitments for emissions reductions2, 3. These countries and others in a newly organized negotiating group, the 'Like Minded Developing Countries', have put equity at the top of the agenda and argued that wealthier countries should take on deeper cuts corresponding to their historical responsibility for greenhouse gas accumulation in the atmosphere4, 5, 6.

To break this now nearly two-decade-old impasse, it is almost certainly necessary to reduce considerably the number of actors required to move simultaneously, and it is most logical to form a group consisting only of the world's largest emitters, rich and poor. A new approach is needed to share the burden and the benefits of steep emissions reductions, engaging the main developing countries without imposing a disproportionate burden on any particular country. For this to be politically feasible, China and the United States must be onboard, and agreed principles of equity must be at its root7. With leadership from the 'G2', other emitters are likely to follow5, 8, 9.

As the relevant literature on regime building10, 11 shows, including on climate change12, 13, the structural power exerted by China and the United States within a deal such as the one proposed by this Perspective, and their high level of social capital embedded in interstate networks, could induce laggards to join collective action for international emissions reductions. That is, when China and the United States join the 28 countries of the European Union, the 48 Least Developed Countries (LDC), the 44 members of the Association of Small Island States (AOSIS) and other groups moving towards ambitious binding commitments to reduce their emissions, emerging global norms and fear of isolation may bring along some key remaining resisting countries. Given the failure of other approaches, such an effort is certainly worth the attempt.

We stress two points at the start. First, the climate crisis requires the most effective possible emissions abatement effort in order to stabilize the concentrations of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere at a safe level, as agreed by Article 2 of the 1992 United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). Key observers have argued that it is in fact morally superior to look for a course of action that is likely to be politically feasible rather than a perfect one without chance of enactment14, 15.

Second, given the strong relationship between cumulative emissions and global warming16, 17, the more emissions reductions are delayed, the less any climate targets become achievable: therefore the faster collective action is agreed, the more effective it will be, and the less severe emissions reductions will need to be16.

In brief, to address climate change meaningfully, humanity must undertake a complicated and costly collective effort: steeply and quickly reducing global emissions. Hence the urgency of a compromise capable of stimulating key players to swiftly overcome their inertia in order to break the current gridlock and promote effective emissions abatements.

This article develops a compromise to international emissions reductions, based on four core elements for sharing the remaining carbon budget: (1) limiting initial action to the Major Economies Forum (MEF) members, 13 economies responsible for more than 80% of fossil fuel emissions; (2) using consumption-based carbon accounting; (3) applying equity principles of responsibility and capability to apportion the burden of emissions reductions; (4) bringing this deal back to the UN negotiations for wider adoption.

None of these elements is itself new, but this particular combination is. The originality of the proposed approach lies in the nature of its explicit compromise that, in fact, is intended to nudge parties with conflicting objectives to give up part of their narrow short-term interests for the achievement of climate stabilization. To this end, we argue that states — which are the primary unitary actors in international regimes — pursue coordinated efforts for reducing emissions mainly based on interests aimed at material objectives18, 19. In particular, we are sympathetic to a neorealist perspective in international climate politics9, 20. Such a resurgent approach, known as neoclassical realism, besides stressing the importance of structural power, material factors, and in particular of relative gains, takes account systematically of the multiplicity of constituents and levels of international cooperation21, and allows room for moral concerns, whose role is pivotal for the political feasibility of our proposed compromise.

According to the neorealist perspective adopted, relative gains matter in regard to emissions reductions especially for the most powerful countries, China and the United States22, 23. Together these two represent the 'great powers' that currently dominate international climate politics9, 24. As shown later, in terms of burden of emissions reductions, our morally grounded compromise somewhat favours China but without exceedingly penalizing the United States. It is most demanding only for the European Union, the third key actor; but the European Union would seem willing to take on relatively greater efforts towards emission reductions in exchange for recuperating a pragmatic and strategic role in global climate policy25.

Thus our compromise includes considerations of the multifaceted factors that shape international cooperation on emissions reductions, and takes account of the socioeconomic facts that determine its political feasibility in MEF member countries, consistent with the provisions of the neorealist approach. For these reasons, we argue, the very nature and articulation of our compromise could help to advance collective action to limit emissions.

The four elements of our proposed compromise are outlined below.

Twenty years of painful negotiations among the 195 parties to the UNFCCC show that a deal for abating emissions will probably need to be struck initially in a setting with a limited number of actors24, 26. Consistent with this, with the objective of assisting cooperation among major economies on climate change and energy issues, the MEF was established in March 2009. Scholars with knowledge beyond climate negotiations point out that nearly every important international negotiation has required a 'great powers' leadership group such as this to succeed9, 24.

The MEF includes 16 countries and the European Union. Four MEF members — France, Germany, Italy and the United Kingdom — are excluded from our calculations to avoid double counting, since they belong to the European Union. The 13 MEF members considered here are all of the largest emitters in the world, and their 1990–2010 cumulative consumption-based emissions of CO2 from fossil fuel combustion amount to 81.3% of global cumulative emissions (Table 1).

Table 1: MEF members' cumulative consumption-based emissions, 1990–2010.

The production-based emissions accounting upon which the Kyoto Protocol was built penalizes economies where carbon-intensive stages in globalized production chains take place33. Production-based accounting systems can encourage a shift in consumption of carbon-intensive products towards cheaper imported substitutes34 and incentivize the off-shoring of carbon-intensive production stages from the regulated parts of the world economy35. Such carbon leakage, known as 'weak' or 'indirect', has been shown, in fact, to be largely the result of the relocation of industry to the global south for other reasons, such as cheaper labour costs36, 37.

In our view a more effective, feasible and fairer deal for reducing emissions should instead rely on consumption-based carbon accounting. Consumption-based accounting measures emissions deriving from the final use of goods and services. It is calculated by deducting from a country's production-based inventories emissions embodied in exports, and adding emissions embodied in imports.

Consumption-based inventories make it possible to divide MEF members into two categories: carbon exporters and carbon importers (Table 2). The relevant literature35, 38, 39 shows consistently that carbon-exporting economies, when compared with carbon-importing economies, are in a situation of systematic disadvantage in relation to the benefits deriving from the exploitation of their resources. Most importantly, framing emissions in consumption- rather than in production-based terms reduces carbon leakage40, 41, is generally considered fairer40, 41, encourages participation in and increase flexibility of agreements7, 40, 42 and eventually favours the transition to a much-needed green economy40.

Table 2: Carbon-exporting and -importing MEF members.

Moral concerns have long been considered unavoidable for moving climate negotiations forward46. Accordingly, in order to improve the feasibility of our compromise, the distribution of the burden of emissions reductions required by the carbon budget should be calculated on the basis of MEF members' responsibility and capability, the core ethical principles of the UNFCCC which still play a central role in the debate on mitigation47, 48, 49.

The principle of responsibility for past emissions50, 51, 52, the climate variant of the much-cited 'polluter pays' principle, basically responds to the straightforward logic that those who created this mess must also assume the cost of cleaning it up53. Scholars upholding the principle of responsibility basically claim that ignoring responsibility would be to act in favour of people who lived in the past in heavy-emitter industrialized countries, and to discriminate against those now, and in the future, living in developing countries54, 55. The principle of responsibility for past emissions faces conceptual and practical difficulties in the context of emissions abatements50, 51, 52, 56, 57, 58. Nonetheless, such a principle can succeed if a clear framework for it is negotiated57 in a dynamic context47. Decision 1/CP.16 adopted in 2010 in Cancún acknowledged for the first time historical responsibility as a cornerstone of negotiations under the UNFCCC57. Accordingly, the Durban Platform for Enhanced Action, despite the lack of direct reference to historical responsibility, opened the way for a nuanced understanding of the notion of responsibility based on past emissions that goes beyond the mere distinction between developed and developing countries47, 56. In fact, the compromise proposed here ultimately upholds the adoption, in the non-ideal world of negotiations on emissions reductions, of a principle of responsibility put into practice according to a short-horizon 'polluter pays' principle uniformly applicable to all MEF members, as explained in what follows.

The principle of capability, known in the scientific literature also as the 'ability to pay' principle58, is forward-looking and demands that the currently most advantaged actors bear the largest quota of mitigation costs because of their greater wealth (in terms of welfare levels) and capacities (in terms of institutions, technology, infrastructures, and skills). In the context of our compromise, capability is normatively understood as the ability of a state to undergo an onerous obligation without suffering a disproportionate welfare sacrifice59. In climate policy discussions a country's current GDP per capita is often used as a proxy for its capability.

On theoretical grounds, such a flexible approach based on responsibility and capability is for both developed and developing countries in the MEF a true compromise in itself60. First, it addresses a requirement of some wealthy developed countries by softening the rigid dichotomy of countries with and without binding duty on emissions reductions57, by bringing developing, relatively low-responsibility countries in the MEF — who have long refused any involvement of this kind — into the leadership group in tackling climate change. To the developing countries in the MEF, some of whom have demanded accounting for historical responsibility back to 1850, the developed, high-responsibility countries acknowledge, against their long-standing non-recognition, cumulative emissions since 1990, the baseline for the Kyoto Protocol and the time at which climate change became well known57. The year 1990 is also the date back to which we have accepted estimates of consumption-based emissions, a core element of this compromise, and one that benefits most developing countries. Thus each side is giving, and receiving, concessions.

The proposed compromise will have immediate impact by developing a solution for 81% of the problem of excessive greenhouse gas emissions; to address the other 19% and cement its recognition in the global community it must eventually be brought back into the wider group of non-MEF members and formalized under the UNFCCC. In this context, non-MEF countries would have no initial emission limits, in order to favour the right to sustainable development of poorer countries sanctioned by the Convention. For wealthier non-MEF members, we expect rapid expansion of commitments, if they fear exclusion from trade in the MEF countries, or shaming or isolation under emerging global norms of what constitutes appropriate behaviour.

We suggest that countries with similar national circumstances such as climate zone and current export profile be placed into broad groups60. The expectations of individual countries should be in line with those of others in their group. This idea is similar to a proposal for National Schedules put forward by the Australian government in the months before the 2009 Copenhagen negotiations. Broadly, expectations of emissions reductions for each group of countries should be based on responsibility and capability, as put into practice by this compromise.

The affluent countries, both MEF and non-MEF, should also have a moral and practical duty to extend a green ladder to poorer countries outside the MEF for realizing their equitable access to sustainable development, through green technology transfer, sufficient and predictable financial assistance, technical and institutional support, and capacity building. Given potential difficulties of putting in place effective MRV systems, particularly in more deprived non-MEF members, richer countries would have a further obligation to provide transition assistance — tools, methodologies, training and knowledge — for collecting and calculating consumption-based figures. This practice is already established for the UN-REDD programme for reducing deforestation with support of the

URL: http://www.nature.com/nclimate/journal/v4/n7/full/nclimate2259.html
Citation statistics:
资源类型: 期刊论文
标识符: http://119.78.100.158/handle/2HF3EXSE/5100
Appears in Collections:气候变化事实与影响
科学计划与规划
气候变化与战略

Files in This Item:
File Name/ File Size Content Type Version Access License
nclimate2259.pdf(762KB)期刊论文作者接受稿开放获取View Download

Recommended Citation:
Marco Grasso. A compromise to break the climate impasse[J]. Nature Climate Change,2014-06-08,Volume:4:Pages:543;549 (2014).
Service
Recommend this item
Sava as my favorate item
Show this item's statistics
Export Endnote File
Google Scholar
Similar articles in Google Scholar
[Marco Grasso]'s Articles
百度学术
Similar articles in Baidu Scholar
[Marco Grasso]'s Articles
CSDL cross search
Similar articles in CSDL Cross Search
[Marco Grasso]‘s Articles
Related Copyright Policies
Null
收藏/分享
文件名: nclimate2259.pdf
格式: Adobe PDF
此文件暂不支持浏览
所有评论 (0)
暂无评论
 

Items in IR are protected by copyright, with all rights reserved, unless otherwise indicated.