globalchange  > 气候变化事实与影响
DOI: doi:10.1038/nclimate2570
论文题名:
Stochastic integrated assessment of climate tipping points indicates the need for strict climate policy
作者: Thomas S. Lontzek
刊名: Nature Climate Change
ISSN: 1758-987X
EISSN: 1758-7107
出版年: 2015-03-23
卷: Volume:5, 页码:Pages:441;444 (2015)
语种: 英语
英文关键词: Governance ; Climate-change mitigation ; Climate-change policy ; Climate-change mitigation
英文摘要:

Perhaps the most ‘dangerous aspect of future climate change is the possibility that human activities will push parts of the climate system past tipping points, leading to irreversible impacts1. The likelihood of such large-scale singular events2 is expected to increase with global warming1, 2, 3, but is fundamentally uncertain4. A key question is how should the uncertainty surrounding tipping events1, 5 affect climate policy? We address this using a stochastic integrated assessment model6, based on the widely used deterministic DICE model7. The temperature-dependent likelihood of tipping is calibrated using expert opinions3, which we find to be internally consistent. The irreversible impacts of tipping events are assumed to accumulate steadily over time (rather than instantaneously8, 9, 10, 11), consistent with scientific understanding1, 5. Even with conservative assumptions about the rate and impacts of a stochastic tipping event, todays optimal carbon tax is increased by ~50%. For a plausibly rapid, high-impact tipping event, todays optimal carbon tax is increased by >200%. The additional carbon tax to delay climate tipping grows at only about half the rate of the baseline carbon tax. This implies that the effective discount rate for the costs of stochastic climate tipping is much lower than the discount rate7, 12, 13 for deterministic climate damages. Our results support recent suggestions that the costs of carbon emission used to inform policy12, 13 are being underestimated14, 15, 16, and that uncertain future climate damages should be discounted at a low rate17, 18, 19, 20.

Integrated assessment models (IAMs) are key tools to assist climate policymaking7, 12, 13, which attempt to capture two-way interactions between climate and society. There is much debate over what discount rate to assume for evaluating future damages due to global temperature rise17, which in turn partly determines how much we should be willing to pay now to avoid or delay those damages. The Stern Review21 followed a prescriptive (and controversial22, 23, 24) approach; based on ethical arguments it assumed a near-zero rate for discounting the utility of future generations, implying a low discount rate for monetized damages of climate change and a high willingness to pay now.  In contrast, studies using a descriptive approach7, 12, 13 generally evaluate the costs of climate change using much higher market rates of return as discount rates. Most studies are deterministic, but uncertainty will also affect the rate at which future levels of climate damage are discounted17, 18, 19, 20. Climate tipping points and their impacts are a key source of uncertainty, for several reasons1, 3, 4. First, our knowledge of thresholds, in terms of, for example, regional warming, is imperfect, and the mapping from global temperature rise to regional thresholds is also uncertain. Second, even if we knew a tipping point precisely, stochastic internal variability in the climate system could trigger tipping at a range of times and corresponding global temperatures4. Several IAM approaches to model climate tipping points are fundamentally deterministic8, 9, 14, 25, 26, whereas only a few studies include stochastic climate damages10, 11, 27 (see Supplementary Discussion). In common with deterministic IAMs, they generally assume10, 11 that the impacts of passing a tipping point are felt instantaneously, whereas in reality impacts will accumulate over time at a rate determined by the dynamics of the system that has been tipped1. One recent study27 assumes that tipping instantaneously increases climate sensitivity or weakens carbon sinks, which then causes damages to accumulate at an increased rate; but this is scientifically questionable (see Supplementary Discussion) and leads to increased discounting of future damages27.

Here, we examine how a more realistic treatment of stochastic climate tipping points affects the optimal policy choice, including the discount rate to evaluate future damages. Our stochastic integrated assessment model6, DSICE (Fig. 1a), builds on the deterministic Dynamic Integrated Climate and Economy (DICE) model7 (2007 version) as used in the 2010 US federal assessment of the social cost of carbon12. The federal assessment13 and the DICE model28 have since been updated, in ways that tend to increase the estimated social cost of carbon (see Supplementary Methods). Hence the reader should focus on our relative changes in carbon tax due to stochastic climate tipping more than the absolute values.

Figure 1: Schematic of the DSICE model.
Schematic of the DSICE model.

a, The forward-looking decision-maker (social planner) chooses mitigation and consumption to maximize the sum of discounted expected utilities over some time horizon. Increased mitigation must be traded off against consumption and savings. Global warming adversely impacts the economy and increases the probability of a tipping point with additional irreversible economic impacts. b, The length of the pre-tipping phase is stochastic, and its likelihood depends on global warming. Once tipping is triggered, damages increase linearly over a specified transition time (5–500 years here) to a specified final level (2.5–20% of World GDP here).

We use DSICE (ref. 6), a multidimensional stochastic integrated assessment model (IAM) of climate and the economy, based on the DICE model7. DICE has been applied in numerous studies, for example, refs 9, 14, 26, and the main drivers of its behaviour have been analysed7. DSICE computes the optimal, global greenhouse gas emission reduction. Higher emission control at present mitigates the damage from climate change in the future but limits consumption and/or capital investment today. The global economy (the social planner) is set to weigh these costs and benefits of emission control to maximize the expected present value of global social welfare. DSICE includes the possibility of a climate tipping point with potential damages to economic output. The occurrence of a climate tipping point is modelled by a Markov process (with a hazard rate) and its timing is not known at times of decisions. Because DSICE is a stochastic model, it can compute the optimal policy response—that is, a tax on carbon emissions to address the uncertain climate tipping event. See Supplementary Methods for a full model description.

The hazard rate for a tipping event represents the conditional probability that a tipping point will occur in a particular year given the actual degree of global warming in that year (above year 2000). Previous work3 from a range of experts has elicited imprecise cumulative probabilities for passing five different tipping points under three different temperature corridors up to the year 2200. Each temperature corridor spans an uncertainty range, and together they range over 0–8 °C warming (above year 2000) depending on the year and the scenario. Here, we calibrate the hazard rate for the tipping event by reverse engineering the contemporaneous conditional probability of tipping from the cumulative probabilities from the expert elicitation study3. See Supplementary Methods for full details of the hazard rate calibration.

  1. Lenton, T. M. et al. Tipping elements in the Earths climate system. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 105, 17861793 (2008).
  2. IPCC Climate Change 2014: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability (eds Field, C. B. et al.) (Cambridge Univ. Press, 2014).
  3. Kriegler, E., Hall, J. W., Held, H., Dawson, R. & Schellnhuber, H. J. Imprecise probability assessment of tipping points in the climate system. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 106, 50415046 (2009).
  4. Lenton, T. M. Early warning of climate tipping points. Nature Clim. Change 1, 201209 (2011).
  5. Lenton, T. M. & Ciscar, J-C. Integrating tipping points into climate impact assessments. Climatic Change 117, 585597 (2013).
  6. Cai, Y., Judd, K. L. & Lontzek, T. S. The Social Cost of Stochastic and Irreversible Climate Change (National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 18704, NBER, 2013).
  7. Nordhaus, W. D. A Question of Balance: Weighing the Options on Global Warming Policies (Yale Univ. Press, 2008).
  8. Mastrandrea, M. D. & Schneider, S. H. Integrated assessment of abrupt climatic changes. Clim. Policy 1, 433449 (2001).
  9. Kosugi, T. Integrated assessment for setting greenhouse gas emission targets under the condition of great uncertainty about the probability and impact of abrupt climate change. J. Environ. Inform. 14,
URL: http://www.nature.com/nclimate/journal/v5/n5/full/nclimate2570.html
Citation statistics:
资源类型: 期刊论文
标识符: http://119.78.100.158/handle/2HF3EXSE/4815
Appears in Collections:气候变化事实与影响
科学计划与规划
气候变化与战略

Files in This Item:
File Name/ File Size Content Type Version Access License
nclimate2570.pdf(443KB)期刊论文作者接受稿开放获取View Download

Recommended Citation:
Thomas S. Lontzek. Stochastic integrated assessment of climate tipping points indicates the need for strict climate policy[J]. Nature Climate Change,2015-03-23,Volume:5:Pages:441;444 (2015).
Service
Recommend this item
Sava as my favorate item
Show this item's statistics
Export Endnote File
Google Scholar
Similar articles in Google Scholar
[Thomas S. Lontzek]'s Articles
百度学术
Similar articles in Baidu Scholar
[Thomas S. Lontzek]'s Articles
CSDL cross search
Similar articles in CSDL Cross Search
[Thomas S. Lontzek]‘s Articles
Related Copyright Policies
Null
收藏/分享
文件名: nclimate2570.pdf
格式: Adobe PDF
此文件暂不支持浏览
所有评论 (0)
暂无评论
 

Items in IR are protected by copyright, with all rights reserved, unless otherwise indicated.